The Durbin Amendment Explained as simply as possible

The Durbin Amendment Explained

The Durbin Amendment, a last-minute addition to the Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act of 2010, has sparked fierce debate. [Update June 20th, 2011: A recent challenge to the Durbin Amendment, mounted by Senator Jon Tester (D-Montana), would have delayed the regulations by a year while the Federal Reserve studied their effect on small banks and credit unions. While the bill gained 54 votes in the Senate, it fell short of the 60 votes needed to end a filibuster. Now that the Durbin Amendment will be implemented as planned, banks and card networks are scurrying to replace lost revenue while mounting court challenges.]
The amendment is rather complex, but the two provisions that are still being debated, pending the Federal Reserve’s July 21, 2011 decision, are:
1. A cap of 7 to 12 cents on most debit card swipe fees, a decline of about 80% from present levels
2. The introduction of competition, by giving merchants a choice as to which debit network they process transactions over. For example, present arrangements effectively force merchants to process many Visa transactions over the STAR network, even if competitors like PULSE and NYCE offer to conduct the same transaction at a lower processing price.
The provisions that are already in place include:
1. Merchants can impose a $10 minimum on credit card transactions (this number can be adjusted by the Fed as they see fit). Previously, Visa and MasterCard banned this practice in their merchant agreements.
2. Merchants are allowed to give discounts at the register to those who pay with cash or debit cards. Previously, Visa and MasterCard banned this practice in their merchant agreements.
Banks and credit unions are against the amendment, because debit card swipe fees mostly accrue to the financial institution that issued the debit card. Card issuing banks typically take in about 1.3% of every dollar you spend on your debit card, as a fee from the merchant. This amounts to nearly $3 billion a year of very high profit margin revenue for Bank of America, for example, a number which looks to decline by ~80% unless Congres, the Department of Justice, or the Federal Reserve intervenes.
This fee is supposed to cover the risk of fraud, transactional costs, and other overhead, but due to the lack of negotiating power on the merchant side, the fee is now a major source of profit margin at every bank that offers checking accounts. Subsequently, competition between banks has caused this profit center to be used in subsidizing free premium services, like free checking accounts and surcharge-free ATMs. If this fee were to drop to 7-12 cents per transaction, as proposed by the amendment, this would create a large wealth transfer from debit card issuers to merchants, and will likely end many free premium services at banks.
The amendment’s supporters in Congress theorize that the wealth transfer from the banks to the merchants will result in lower prices for all consumers, as competitive forces between merchants force them to pass on lower costs to customers, in the form of lower prices.
Protecting The Little Guy, Fail
The swipe fee cap technically exempts financial institutions with assets of $10 billion or less. In theory, this exempts all but 3 out of the 7,000+ credit unions. However, credit unions are aggressively lobbying against the amendment. They fear that the provision requiring multiple network routing options will make the small bank interchange cap exemption impossible to enforce. For example, Visa already promised to honor the two-tier pricing system, and would process a small institution’s transaction at the current price. However, the networks are not required to differentiate between large and small banks. Even if Visa’s STAR network offered to route a debit transaction at the “exempt” 1.5% debit interchange rate, the existence of a competitive option allows the merchant to route the transaction through NYCE instead for 12 cents. Therefore the credit union would receive some fraction of 12 cents for the transaction, rather than ~1.3% of the transaction.
The Visa-MasterCard Duopoly
Proponents of the amendment allege that merchant interchange fees have skyrocketed relative to the cost of processing the transactions. The interchange market is largely uncompetitive: Visa and MasterCard effectively set the interchange fees for all merchants. Merchants can choose not to accept Visa and MasterCard, but this is not practical for most. The Durbin amendment’s attempt to reduce prices is two-pronged: first, the mandatory introduction of competition, and second, a limit to fees in order to correct for the market failure resulting from what is essentially a duopoly.
U.S. swipe fees are, overall, uncompetitive when compared to European countries, where anti-trust regulation has broken the chokehold of Visa and MasterCard. U.S. debit interchange fees are higher than the European Union average but not egregiously so; the true effect of uncompetitive pricing is seen in the interchange fees charged on credit card transactions, where the U.S. is by far the highest.
Most notably, the fees on some premium credit cards diverged greatly from the rest of the industry in conjunction with the 2007 IPO’s of both Visa and Mastercard, likely because of pressure to juice profits for public shareholders:

Onerous credit fees are ignored
Because of the difficulty of differentiating prices for goods based on the method of payment, merchants generally factor the exchange fees into the sticker price, or absorb the cost themselves. As a result, whether a consumer pays with cash, debit, credit or rewards credit, he will see the same price (one exception is in gas prices, where the limited number of products offered allows for price differentiation). However, merchant exchange fees for credit cards, and rewards credit cards in particular, are significantly steeper than debit card fees.
One feature of monopoly pricing is that the card network can, as much as they are able, set different prices to maximize how much it believes different groups will pay. So, for example, a Visa Signature Preferred rewards card nets a 2.5% interchange fee at a restaurant (which has little bargaining power), while a Visa Classic transaction may cost a large supermarket only 1.15% (because Visa wouldn’t want to risk, say, Wal-Mart walking away). By comparison, in France, a credit card with an embedded security chip costs all merchants 0.22% of the transaction plus 10 Euro cents, while the least secure (and thus most expensive to cover) method of payment costs 0.3% plus 10 Euro cents (there is virtually no difference by way of fees with Visa versus MasterCard). The intricacies of pricing, and the emphasis on the lucrative, oft-used reward credit cards, speak to market inefficiencies.
Are the fees necessary to fund fraud protection?
The major card networks allege that the interchange fees are necessary for fraud protection efforts, and to limit consumers’ losses in case fraud does occur. However, improving technology should have driven down the cost of fraud protection, not increased it. Jamie Henry, Wal-Mart’s director of payment services, argued that credit card issuers have deliberately kept chip-and-PIN technology from U.S. cards because security improvements would remove the justification for high merchant exchange fees. “Lower interchange would push the industry toward chip-and-PIN. We would see more financial institutions become interested in controlling fraud. It would be more difficult to pass [fraud] costs on to merchants.”
In response to proposed regulation, banks cry foul and threaten tightened credit, higher fees and steeper interest rates should the proposed regulations take effect. Some have also threatened per-transaction spending caps on debit cards, at $50 or $100, rendering debit effectively useless in paying for groceries, restaurants, or plane tickets, and driving customers toward more lucrative credit cards.
However, not-for-profit credit unions are also stalwartly opposed to the amendment, and for much the same reason: they fear that they will have to cut services or increase fees in response to an increased bottom line. They may have more substance to their claims than for-profit banks.
How Durbin hopes to ease the burden on consumers and merchants
The Federal Reserve believes that merchant exchange fees far exceed the cost of fraud protection. They further believe that the steep markups persist because the two major card networks, Visa and MasterCard, have such control over the credit and debit card markets that merchants, card issuers and consumers have no choice but to accept the prices that they set.
In order to correct this, the Fed proposed a cap that it believes accurately reflects the true cost of securing the debit cards used. If they have correctly judged the cap, banks will not suffer a loss to their bottom line, and will continue to provide the same services to consumers while merchants are able to offer better prices. They also introduce competition to previously monopolistic markets by requiring each debit card to be covered by at least two networks. However, the amendment fails to address credit card interchange fees, which are significantly higher than debit.
Although the regulations make an exception for small institutions, this exemption is meaningless as card issuers will have to accept the lowest exchange fee offered, whether or not it covers their security costs. This is an undue burden on credit unions, which are generally smaller and pay more to protect their customers.
This is not to say that the “swipe” fees are grossly overpriced, and that government reform of the market will not benefit consumers. However, the Federal Reserve must be careful to preserve the advantages offered by credit unions.
The following infographic, which we released last April, gives further details about how interchange fees affect merchants and banks:

You might like:

Why the Durbin Amendment will Increase Credit Card Fraud

Chase Revives Debit Rewards Program after Durbin Amendment Delay

Latest Threat to the Durbin Amendment: A $100 Spending Cap on Debit Cards

Durbin Interchange Amendment: Precursor to $132 Annual Fees?

Senate Ruling on the Durbin Amendment

June 10, 2011
Senate Ruling on the Durbin Amendment
Information Details:
The US Senate voted Wednesday to allow the Federal Reserve to implement the $0.12 interchange on debit cards for large banks which was proposed in the Durbin Amendment. Large issuing banks/credit unions of a designated size would have this rate applied to debit card transactions while smaller issuing banks/credit unions would continue with the current debit card interchange rates. Given the complexity of the amendment, defining the rules for “large” banks and/or credit unions will take more time and the Federal Reserve is expected to provide additional guidelines by July 21, 2011.
We anticipate the Card Brands will release information after July 21, 2011 when the Federal Reserve provides rules and guidelines for implementing the $0.12 interchange on debit transactions.

Reduce Worker Comp costs…

The below is from my friend Bryan Ryndak and may save you money on workers comp

Some companies suffer several thousand dollars per MSD* claim, while others pay only a few hundred dollars per claim. Some enjoy very few claims at all, while others struggle with epidemics. Why such huge differences among employers??

Ryndak’s NO-LOST-TIME program teaches companies how to address injuries and costs as two separate issues, selecting from a long list of proven tactics to fit each work area.

We bring to the workplace customized, affordable NO-LOST-TIME programs. We are highly experienced at NOT upsetting delicate workplace politics. We address Worker Comp claims and costs in ways that can correct attitudes and politics that are often the root of these issues.

The NO-LOST-TIME programs were developed over 20 years while consulting in more than 500 workplaces providing MSD prevention programs. Historically, companies have seen a reduction in MSD lost days of up to 70%.

How…?

Have us spend a day examining your MSD claims and costs issues, leading us to write a detailed assessment and proposed action plan to address root causes of these problems.

We examine OSHA logs to identify trends and implications; analyze past efforts; explore policies and practices that affect costs and outcomes; examine high-risk work areas to identify subtle but critical injury risk factors.

This analysis leads us to produce a targeted ACTION PLAN. This may include manager training to build enlightened decision-making; supervisor training to build commitment-cooperation-attitudes; suggest claims response procedures; suggest ergonomics actions that are affordable and practical; suggest alternatives to ergonomics that can effectively reduce claims; suggest restricted duty processes… and more, all customized to your workplace needs.

Regain Control Now…

Ryndak Physical Therapy (630) 295-9990

*MSD – OSHA term for Musculoskeletal Disorders (includes tendinitis, rotator cuff, carpal tunnel, neck and low back injuries)

Beat the credit card fraudsters!

I hate people that do identity theft and cheat merchants. Don’t forget if you are suspect of a transaction to

-make sure the avs and cvv match
-have them sign a cc auth form (attached) and provide a copy of their driver’s license and front & back of cc
-get a copy of the DL & cc front and back.
-Also call the purchaser’s phone # to confirm the order. You’d be surprised that 90% of the time the phone # is phony and disconnected
-also call the issuing bank phone # on the back of the cc. Surprisingly the phone # usually doesn’t match the name of the issuing bank on the front of the card
-google the purchaser’s name and address to see if it matches and if any fraud shows up
-google the email address-often fraud will show up in regards to that email address
-make sure you ship to the address you did the AVS check on and get a signed proof of delivery or signature at will call.

Bill